바로가기메뉴

본문 바로가기 주메뉴 바로가기

logo

한국 면세점 산업의 구조, 독과점인가?

Is the Korean Duty Free Shop Industry Monopolistic?

The Journal of Distribution Science(JDS) / The Journal of Distribution Science, (P)1738-3110; (E)2093-7717
2016, v.14 no.10, pp.47-57
https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.15722/jds.14.10.201610.47
이희태 (Hannam University)
차문경 (Seoul National University)
  • 다운로드 수
  • 조회수

Abstract

Purpose - This study's purpose is to investigate the market structure of the Korean duty free shop industry that has received recent attention from researchers and practitioners. By raising the question of whether or not the Korean duty free shop industry is unequivocally monopolistic, a wider viewpoint is provided. The study seeks to offer insights and managerial implications for marketers and policy makers who are in charge of regulating major Korean duty free shops. Research design, data, and methodology - The authors use secondary data from various sources, including Korea Customs Service and the Moodie Report, to investigate the structure of the duty free shop industry of Korea. Based on several theories, they present various criteria and statistical evidence such as K-firm concentration ratio, HHI, consumer substitutability, excess profit, and marketing costs. Results - In terms of consumer substitutability, it is difficult to confirm whether or not the Korean duty free shop industry is monopolistic. Notwithstanding monopoly characteristics in terms of market share, neither the company Lotte nor Shilla appear to have market dominating power. It is not easy for either of them to control prices or to achieve a much lower operational profit ratio due to a dominant bargaining power. Moreover, the license is not an economic rent. In this situation, it is not easy for these companies to obtain an excessive profit. Conclusions - Considering that most global duty free shops are trying to go upscale to improve bargaining power, it does not seem likely that rigid regulations are needed in the industry. Even though the Korean duty free industry ostensibly has a monopolistic structure, government and policy-makers should look beyond the surface. They should take global and other reasonable criteria into consideration when they establish or change regulation policies. Thorough understanding and appropriate support are needed for the Korean duty free shop industry. Additionally, duty free shops should position themselves as global companies struggling against unlimited international competition, rather than Korean domestic companies. At the same time, they need to give customers appropriate information about the benefits they provide.

keywords
Duty Free Shops, Market Structure, Market Concentration Index, Market Dominant Enterprise

참고문헌

1.

Albarran, A. B., & Dimmick, J. (1996). Concentration and economics of multiformity in the communication industries. Journal of Media Economics, 9(4), 41-50.

2.

Benham, Lee (1972). The effect of advertising on the price of eyeglasses. Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 37-52.

3.

Carlton, D. W., & Perloff, J. M. (2004). Modern industrial organization (4th international ed.). Indiana, USA:Addison-Wesley.

4.

Biz Chosun (2016). The wasteful competition of Korean duty free shops for license every 5 year. Biz Chosun, 30, August, 2016. Retrieved September 2, 2016, from http://biz.chosun.com/site/data/html_dir/2015/11/16/2015111600360.html

5.

Cowling, K., & Mueller, D. C. (1978). The social cost of monopoly power. Economic Journal, 88, 727-748.

6.

Edwards, F. R. (1977). Marginal objectives in regulated industries: expense –preference behavior in banking. Journal of Political Economy, 85(1), 147-162.

7.

Harberger, A. C. (1954). Monopoly and resource allocation. American Economic Review, 44(2), 77-87.

8.

Jenny, F., & Weber, A. (1983). Aggregate welfare loss due to monopoly power in the French economy:some tentative estimates. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 32(2), 113-130.

9.

Kamerschen, D. R. (1996). An estimation of the “welfare losses” from monopoly in the American economy. Economic Inquiry, 4(3), 221-236.

10.

Kang, M. H. (1992). A study on the economic effects of concentration of economic power. Journal of industrial studies, 15, 249-278.

11.

Kim, K. H., Choi, Y., W., & Yoon, Y. S. (2015). A study on foreign tourists’ rural destination selection attributes that affect travel satisfaction and destination loyalty. Korean Journal of Tourism Research, 30(3), 21-40.

12.

Kim, S. H., & Kim, Y. K. (2013). Study on improving the system for the revitalization and efficient management of the local commercial area. Journal of Distribution Science, 11(5), 55-62.

13.

Leibenstein, H. (1966). Allocative efficiency versus x-efficiency. American Economic Review, 56(3), 392-415.

14.

Posner, R. A. (1975). The social cost of monopoly and regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 83(3), 807-828.

15.

Primeaux, W. J. (1977). An assesment of x-efficiency gained through competition. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 59(1), 105-108.

16.

Schwartzman, D. (1960). The burden of monopoly. Journal of Political Economy, 68(6), 627-630.

17.

Shin, S., & Yeo, J. (2013). The estimates of consumer welfare loss due to monopoly and policy implications. Journal of Consumer Studies. 24(20), 71-95.

18.

Siegfried, J. J., & Tiemann, T. K. (1974). The welfare cost of monopoly: an inter-industry analysis. Economic Inquiry, 12(2), 190-202.

19.

Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare cost of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224-232.

20.

Van Der Wurff, R. (2003). Structure, conduct, and performance of the agricultural trade journal market in the Netherlands. The Journal of Media Economics, 16(2), 121-138.

21.

Heraldbiz (2016). The defeat of Korean tourism. Heraldbiz. Retrieved March 29, 2016, from http://biz.heraldcorp.com/view.php?ud=20160329000222

22.

Zhang, J., & Lee, H. Y. (2016). The word-of-mouth effects on the Chinese customers’ choice intention of medical tourism destination. Journal of Distribution Science, 14(7), 21-31.

The Journal of Distribution Science(JDS)