Purpose - Marketing scholars have developed various types of mathematical models for describing marketing phenomenon, because there is no single model comprehensive enough to incorporate all the relevant marketing phenomena. This study tries to summarize the behavioral foundations and the mathematical derivations of the most widely used marketing models and discusses their strategic implications. This study selected four representative marketing models: multinomial logit(MNL) model, elimination-by-aspects(EBA) model, Hauser and Shugan model and Bass diffusion model. Especially, this study focuses on Hauser and Shugan(1983)'s Defender model and discusses the model's behavioral foundation and its implications. Research design, data, and methodology - Of the four selected model, the multinomial logit model is selected as the basic normative model and the other three models are described as descriptive models in contrast. Starting the discussion from the multinomial logit model, this study explains what important strategic variables are incorporated in each of the four models. The IIA(independence of irrelevant alternatives) axiom and Luce choice model is also discussed in relation to the multinomial logit model. The concept of 'efficient frontier' is discussed in relation to Hauser and Shugan's model. Graphs and tables are used to represent the key implications. No empirical study is included. Results - The analyses of the mathematical marketing models are shown to be very useful in understanding the essence of positioning strategy. The multinomial logit model implies the importance of increasing utility or consumer preference level. The EBA model implies the importance of lowering the inter-brand similarity and dominating the competitors. Hauser and Shugan model implies the importance of considering customer heterogeneity distribution in selecting the target market. Conclusions - It is shown that the concepts of 'efficient frontier' is useful in understanding the effectiveness of positioning strategy. Market positioning can be understood as occupying some place on the efficient frontier. The important strategic implications can be summarized as follows: Always try to increase customer preference by providing what they value, and differentiate from competing alternatives as much as possible. The best positioning strategy is to dominate all the competitors and the worst is to be dominated by the competitors.
Bass, F. M. (1969). A New Product Growth Model for Consumer Durables. Management Science, 15(4), 216-227.
Bass, F. M. (1980). The Relationship Between Diffusion Rates, Experience Curves, and Demand Elasticities for Consumer Durable Technological Innovations. Journal of Business, 53(3), 51-67.
Bass, F. M., Jain, D., & Krishnan, T. (2000). Modeling the Marketing-Mix Influence in New-Product Diffusion. In V. Mahajan, E. Muller & Y. Wind(eds.), New-Product Diffusion Models, Boston, MA.: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Carpenter, G. S., & Nakamoto, K. (1989). Consumer Preference Formation and Pioneering Advantage. Journal of Marketing Research, 26(3), 285-298.
Chernev, A. (1997). The Effect of Common Features on Brand Choice: Moderating Role of Attribute Importance. Journal of Consumer Research. 23(4), 304-311.
Chernev, A. (2001). The Impact of Common Features on Consumer Preferences: A Case of Confirmatory Reasoning. Journal of Consumer Research, 27(4), 475-488.
Debreu, G. (1960). Review of R. D. Luce, Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis. American Economic Review, 50, 186-188.
Guadagni, P. M., & Little, J. D. C. Little (1983). A Logit Model of Brand Choice Calibrated on Scanner Data. Marketing Science, 2(3), 203-238.
Hauser, J. R., & Shugan, S. M. (1983). Defensive Marketing Strategies. Marketing Science, 2(4), 319-360.
Horsky, D. (1990). The Effects of Income, Price and Information on the Diffusion of New Consumer Durables. Marketing Science, 9(4), 342-365.
Horsky, D., & Simon, L. S. (1983). Advertising and the Diffusion of New Products. Marketing Science, 2(1), 1-18.
Huber, J., Payne, J. W., & Puto, C. (1982). Adding Asymmetrically Dominated Alternatives: Violations of Regularity and Similarity Hypothesis. Journal of Consumer Research, 9(1), 90-98.
Kalish, S. (1985). A New Product Adoption Model with Pricing, Advertising, and Uncertainty. Management Science, 31, 1569-1585.
Krantz, D. H. (1967). Rational Distance Functions for Multidimensional Scaling. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 4(2), 226-245.
Lilien, G. L., Kotler, P., & Moorthy, K. S. (1992). Marketing Models. Englewood Cliffs, NJ.: Prentice Hall.
Lilien, G. L., & Rangaswamy A. (2005). Marketing Engineering: Computed-Assisted Marketing Analysis and Planning(2nd), New Jersey: Prentice Hall.
Little, J. D. C. (1979). Aggregate Advertising Models: The State of the Art. Operations Research, 27(4), 629-667.
Little, J. D. C. (1970). Models and Managers: The Concept of a Decision Calculus. Management Science, 16(8), B466-B485.
Louviere, J., Hensher, D. A., & Swait, J. D. (2000). Stated Choice Methods: Analysis and Application, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Luce, R. D. (1959). Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Marschak, J. (1960). Binary Choice Constraints on Random Utility Indicators. in K. Arrow, Stanford Symposium of Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences, Stanford: Standford University Press.
McFadden, D. (1973). Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior. in P. Zarembka, Frontiers in Econometrics Applications, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Montgomery, H. (1989). From Cognition to Action: The Search for Dominance in Decision Making. in H. Montgomery & O. Svenson (eds.), Process and Structure in Human Decision Making, New York: Wiley.
Montgomery, C. A. (2012). The Strategist: Be the Leader Your Business Needs, Harper Collins Publishers.
Restle, R. (1961). Psychology of Judgment and Choice, New York: Wiley.
Robinson, B., & Lakhani C. (1975). Dynamic Price Models for New Product Planning. Management Science, 21(10), 1113-1122.
Rooderkerk, R. P., Van Heerde, H. J., & Bijmolt, T. H. A. (2011). Incorporating Context Effects into a Choice Model. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(4), 767-780.
Rosch E., & Mervis, C. B. (1975). Family Resemblances: Studies in the Internal Structure of Categories. Cognitive Psychology, 7(5), 573-605.
Simonson, I. (1989). Choice Based on Reasons: The Case of Attraction and Compromise Effects. Journal of Consumer Research, 16(2), 158-174.
Tellis, J., & Golder, P. N. (2001), Will and Vision, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Thurstone, L. L. (1927). A Law of Comparative Judgment. Psychological Review, 34(4), 273-286.
Tversky, A. (1972). Elimination by Aspects: A Theory of Choice, Psychological Review, 79(4), 281-299.
Usher, M., & McClelland, J. L. (2004). Loss Aversion and Inhibition in Dynamical Models of Multialternative Choice. Psychological Review, 111(3), 757-769.
Veryzer, R. W., & Hutchinson, J. W. (1998). The influence of Unity and Prototypicality on Aethetic Responses to New Product Design. Journal of Consumer Research, 24(4), 374-394.
Won, E. J. S. (2012). A Theoretical Investigation on the Attraction Effect Using the Elimination-by-Aspects Model Incorporating Higher Preference for Shared Features. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 56(5), 386-391.
Won, J. S. (2011). A Theoretical Investigation on the Effects of Dominance and Survival Probabilities on the Brands’ Market Shares. Journal of Commodity Science and Technology, 29(4), 19-32.
Won, J. S. (2013A). A Critical Review on Behavioral Economics with a Focus on Prospect Theory and EBA Model. Journal of Distribution Science, 11(5), 63-76.
Won, J. S. (2013B). Comparative Analyses of Mass Marketing and Target Marketing Based on Price Elasticity and Production Cost. Journal of Distribution Science, 11(4), 61-72.
Won, J. S. (2014). Analysis of the Concept of Positioning from the Perspective of Behavioral Economics. Journal of Product Research, 32(5), 157-177.